This blog piece intends to introduce a new add-in (i.e. COINCIDENT) that estimates a coincident index within a dynamic factor modeling framework.
Table of Contents
- Introduction
- Single Factor Model Specification
- Application to Sectoral Inflation Expectations
- Files
- References
Introduction
Stock and Watson (1989) proposed a dynamic factor analysis to develop a coincident index that measures the state of overall economic activity. The model adopted by authors “…is based on the notion that comovements in many macroeconomic variables have a common element that can be captured by a single underlying, unobserved variable.” This single-index framework is quite flexible and can effectively be used for general purpose dimensional reduction analysis, where variables of interest are assumed to share a common factor.Single Dynamic Factor Model Specification
Let’s denote $y_{i,t}$ as the variables of interest in logarithms ($i = 1, 2,\ldots,n$) and $\Delta$ as the difference operator. Then the dynamic factor framework can be outlined as follows: \begin{align*} \Delta y_{i,t} &= \alpha_i + \beta_i C_t + \nu_{i,t} \\ C_t &= \sum_{m=1}^{p} \rho_m C_{t-m} + \eta_t, \quad \eta_t \sim \text{NID}(0, \sigma_\eta^2) \\ \nu_{i,t} &= \sum_{m=1}^{k} \gamma_m \nu_{i,t-m} + \varepsilon_{i,t}, \quad \varepsilon_{i,t} \sim \text{NID}(0, \sigma_{\nu,i}^2) \end{align*} Here, $C_t$, is the latent common factor with AR($p$) dynamics that drives our observed time series variables contemporaneously (assuming $p=1$ and $\rho_m=1$ will impose a random walk). Measurement errors, $ν_{i,t}$, are also defined to have AR($k$) dynamics (assuming $k=1$ and $\gamma_m=0$ will impose a white noise). In case there is a stochastic trend component that is common to each variable, then no transformation is needed (i.e. $y_{i,t}$).Application to Sectoral Inflation Expectations
Economic agents may differ with respect to their inflation expectations as they are exposed to different set of items in the CPI basket. They may also assign different weights to changes in the prices of their preferred goods and services. Still, it is safe to assume that there might be a common component that has an impact on each agent’s perception or behavior towards price changes (COINCIDENT_DATA.WF1).Figure 1 below shows the 12-months ahead expectations of annual inflation for market professionals, firms and households in Türkiye (COINCIDENT_EXAMPLE.PRG). Households have the highest inflation expectations, whereas market professionals have the lowest. There are large differences in the levels of expectations, but correlations among them are higher than 0.95.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Until the pandemic, average of sectoral expectations systematically overshoots the actual data, whereas estimated index does a better job in fitting. Realization of very high inflation prints thereafter causes significant jumps in both indicators, but the index still outperforms the average of sectoral expectations in capturing the level shift until the start of disinflation (see Figure 4).
|
|
Files
References
- Stock, J. H., and Watson, M. W., (1989), "New Indexes of Coincident and Leading Economic Indicators", NBER Macroeconomics Annual, pp. 351-94.
No comments:
Post a Comment